SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
vol.12 número2Da lógica ao lucro: uma reflexão sobre a aplicabilidade da lógica dominada por serviço ao ramo hoteleiroA convergência da sustentabilidade ambiental com os cruzeiros marítimos em dois momentos: na pesquisa acadêmica e na comunicação das empresas do setor índice de autoresíndice de assuntospesquisa de artigos
Home Pagelista alfabética de periódicos  

Serviços Personalizados

Journal

Artigo

Indicadores

Links relacionados

  • Não possue artigos similaresSimilares em SciELO

Compartilhar


Revista Brasileira de Pesquisa em Turismo

versão On-line ISSN 1982-6125

Rev. Bras. Pesq. Tur. vol.12 no.2 São Paulo Mai./Ago. 2018

http://dx.doi.org/10.7784/rbtur.v12i2.1392 

Paper

Relational economic geography and its use in tourism clusters studies

La geografía económica relacional y su aplicación en los estudios de aglomerados productivos del turismo

Adriana Fumi Chim-Miki1 
http://orcid.org/0000-0001-7685-2718

Thays Cristina Domareski Ruiz2 
http://orcid.org/0000-0002-0183-2752

1Federal University of Campina Grande (UFCG), Paraíba. Bibliographic Research for Development of the theoretical basis of the paper; Methodology; Analysis of the paper; Elaboration of figures and comparative tables;

2Federal University of Paraná (UFPR), Curitiba, PR. Bibliographic Research for development of the theoretical basis of the paper; Literature review; Analysis and discussion of the paper; Final review.

Abstract

This paper presents the evolution of the theory of Relational Economic Geography (REG) as a theoretical framework for the regional analysis and tourism destinations analysis. It discusses the origin, foundations, conceptualization trends, and criticism of this perspective. It also contextualizes through a comparison between the analyses of tourism destinations based on productive clusters (networks, districts, clusters, and local productive arrangements) and analysis from the REG perspective. It is a qualitative study, of theoretical and conceptual review, whose objective is to verify if REG is either a complementary perspective to the classic studies of productive agglomerations or a perspective that can substitute them, addressing the gaps that have been pointed out by the researchers. The findings suggest that REG can be used in tourism destination studies, regardless of the territorial/ productive organization. Also, the REG approach can generate tools to translate the relational thinking, taking it out of abstraction and bringing this theoretical concept into the practice of territorial management of tourism destination.

Keywords: Relational Economic Geography; Tourism Destination; Agglomeration Productive Systems; Relational thinking

Resumen

Este artículo muestra la evolución de la teoria de la Geografía Económica Relacional (GER) como una base teórica de análisis regional y de destinos turísticos. Se presenta los orígenes, fundamentos, tendencias de conceptualización y críticas de esta perspectiva. También una contextualización es presentada a través de una comparación entre los análisis de destinos turísticos basadas en aglomerados productivos (redes, distritos, clústeres) y el análisis por la perspectiva da GER. Es un estudio cualitativo, con revisión teórica y conceptual, que objetiva verificar si la GER es una perspectiva complementar a los clásicos estudios de aglomeraciones productivas o si es una perspectiva que puede sustituirlos, mejorando algunas debilidades que han sido apuntadas por los investigadores. Se concluí que la GER puede ser utilizada para estudios de destinos turísticos, independientemente de la forma de organización territorial/productiva que éste tenga. Así como, podrá generar herramientas para traducir el pensamiento relacional, sacándolo de la abstracción y poniendo esta concepción teórica para la práctica de la gestión territorial de los destinos turísticos.

Palabras clave: Geografía Económica Relacional; Destinos Turísticos; Aglomerados productivos; Pensamiento relacional

1 INTRODUCTION

A separation from the neoclassical economic ideas occurred (Bathelt & Glückler, 2003) from the seminal work of Amin and Thrift (2000) that suggested another direction for economic geography borrowing concepts from other social sciences. The use of the evolutionary and relational economic perspective in the researches has been growing, opening promising discussions for the development of new theories (Boschma & Frenken, 2010). The topic has attracted the attention of researchers and in April 2009, the Times Higher Education presented a data analysis by Thomson Reuters, Essential Science Indicators (ESI), highlighting "Relational and Evolutionary Economic Geography" as the third most researched topic in social sciences - with 2,232 citations in 41 scientific papers. (Randelli, Romei & Tortora, 2014; Domareski-Ruiz; Chim-Miki & Gândara, 2014).

Relational approaches have been more frequent in contemporary studies and advocated by many scholar leaders (Sunley, 2008). However, severe criticism and doubts still surround this approach, which is presumably new thinking, a paradigm based on theory. Some authors point out that a "wave of enthusiasm" has taken over the theoretical debates compromising the discussion and critical evaluation (Storper, 1997; Boggs & Rantisi, 2003; Overman, 2004; Yeung, 2005; Sunley, 2008).

The relational approach is a dispersed set of theories and ideas that share common characteristics but differ in important respects (Bathelt, 2006). These approaches have been used to analyze modes of economic coordination or governance where there are collaborative and trustful relationships that favor the exchange of knowledge (Jones & Hesterly; Borgatti, 1997; Dyer & Singh, 1998; Rutten, 2004 Capello & Faggian, 2005).

According to scholars, the level of research in Relational Economic Geography (REG) still does not have enough conceptual and methodological basis to have a practical meaning. Also, REG still is incapable of generating conditions of applicability in the real-world context, particularly to become the framework of empirical research. Even so, the approach seems adequate to analyze organizational networks, having the potential to contribute to scientific research and empirical analysis. (Bathelt & Glückler, 2003; Boschma & Frenken, 2006; Boschma & Martin, 2007; Sanz-Ibáñez & Antón Clavé, 2014).

This paper presents and discusses relational thinking, bringing to the academic debate the REG proposal, its origins, and background. It intends to encourage the scientific community to join efforts to consolidate a theoretical framework to allow the use of this approach in several areas. The research was set in tourism, and its primary objective is to discuss whether the use of REG complements or replaces the traditional analysis of tourism destinations that considers them as network, district, cluster or LPA (Local Productive Arrangements).

Tourism was chosen for this discussion because it is a singular economic activity based on the interdependence of actors to compose the destination as an integral product (Della Corte & Sciarelli, 2012). The research is classified as qualitative with a theoretical and conceptual structure which considers the following questions: How can REG contribute to the analysis of tourism destinations? Does REG replace the networks, districts, clusters, and productive agglomerations approaches or does it complement them? Can REG be applied to any productive structure or are there limitations? Thus, this research is characterized as analytical and descriptive, with a qualitative approach based on a theoretical and conceptual review of papers on REG published in Scopus, Web of Science, Science Direct, and Scielo databases. Also, a follow-up of works cited by the authors consulted was done to provide a broad and historical view of REG as a conceptual perspective.

2 RELATIONAL THINKING AS A BASE OF RELATIONAL ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY (REG): ORIGINS AND CONCEPTS

Since the 1990s, economic geogra-phers have conducted studies on the complexity of relations between actors and structures. Also, they have studied how these relations affect the spatial dynamics of economic activities by consolidating the so-called Relational Economic Geography (Amin, 1998; Dicken & Malmberg, 2001; Ettlinger, 2001; Bathelt & Gluckler, 2003; Boggs & Rantisi, 2003). Studies with different contributions and backgrounds have emerged within Economic Geography, highlighting: the relational construction of spatial identity (Amin & Thrift, 2000) and the works related to the so-called "windows of locational opportunity" and "untraded interdependencies" (Scott, 1988; Storper & Walker, 1989). Other approaches came from the contributions of economic sociology with the notions of social embeddedness and trust-based relationships (Granovetter, 1985), and more recently, the social production of knowledge (Faulconbridge, 2006) has been discussed.

Table 1 is extracted from Yeung (2005) that proposed 'rethinking' REG. It synthesizes the relational frameworks analyzed by geographic, economic, and management concepts, leading to a classification of spatial manifestations and concepts currently used in the regional development and competitiveness studies.

Table 1 Relational frameworks in Economic Geography and their antecedents  

Relational frameworks Thematic Concepts Major Authors Spatial Manifestations Antecedents
Relational assets in local and regional development Institutional thickness Ash Amin;
Phil Cooke;
Anders Malmberg;
Ron Martin;
Peter Maskell;
Kevin Morgan;
Allen Scott;
Michael Storper;
Nigel Thrift.
New industrial spaces Evolutionary and institutional economics
Traded and Untraded interdependencies Industrial districts New economic sociology
Agglomeration tendencies Clusters Organizational analysis
Atmosphere and milieu Learning regions Urban studies
Social Capital Marshallian nodes in global cities Political studies of democracy and social movements
Relational embeddedness in networks: social actors, firms and organizations Inter-organizational networks Ash Amin;
Peter Dicken;
Meric Gertler;
J.K.Gibson-Graham;
Gernot Grabher;
Roger Lee;
Linda McDowell;
Jonathan Murdoch;
Nigel Thrift;
Sara Whatmore;
Global-local tensions New economic sociology
Actor networks Differentiated production of organizational space Organizational analysis and management studies
(Global) Production chains Path dependence Poststructuralism and feminist studies
Hybrid and gender relations Hybrid geographies and multiple trajectories Science and technology
Relational scales Geographical scales as relational constructions Neil Brenner;
Kevin Cox;
Bob Jessop;
Jamie Peck;
Neil Smith;
Erik Swyngedouw;
Peter Taylor
Scalar geographies Geography
Social relations as scalar constructs Politics of globalizations Sociology
Rescaling and reterritorialization Urban and region governance Institutional analysis
Social regulations of local labor markets

Source: Yeung (2005)

Sunley (2008) argues that the origins of relational thinking in economic geography can be traced to sociology from the rooting of networks in economic life. The author stresses this thinking has grown in popularity because the contemporary capitalism has become increasingly relational. The changes caused by late capitalism are characterized by the restructuring and globalization of productive processes, generating new forms of coordination between companies (Sanz-Ibáñez & Antón Clavé, 2014). Dicken, Kelly, Olds, and Yeung (2001) consider that the relational perspective is a starting point for the empirical work. Thus, REG stands out as a tool for analyzing regions and how the relational assets can generate advantages for their development (Coe et al., 2004).

The Relational thinking generated from theoretical-empirical approaches and studies can be grouped into four major schools of thought. The emergence of these schools gathered scholars from Economic and Regional Geography that started relational studies. Some examples are shown in Table 2.

Table 2 Schools of Relational Thinking 

School Relational Thinking Authors
United Kingdom School of Evolutionary Geography Contingency in economic action and critical realism; Social realities of economic action; Sophisticated actor-network conceptions; Vision of deterritorialization of knowledge / creation; Relational construction of spatial identity. Massey (1985); Sayer (1992; 2000); Clark (1983); Amin (1994); Thrift (2000a); Lee (2002); Thrift (2000b); Amin & Thrift (2003); Allen (2003); Massey (2004); Amin & Cohendet (2004); Clark & Tracey (2004).
California School of Economic Geography Forces of the economic agents to create spaces; Windows of locational opportunity; Concept of "Holy Trinity" (Technology, organization, and territory); Concept of non-negotiated interdependencies. Walker & Storper (1981); Scott (1988); Storper & Walker (1989); Storper (1997); Storper & Venables (2004).
Manchester School of Global Production Networks The conception of economic action network; Global connectivity; Socio-institutional aspects and cultural immersion in the international economic interaction. Yeung (1998); Dicken et al. (2001); Dicken & Malmberg (2001); Henderson et al. (2002); Coe & Bunnell (2003); Dicken (2005).
German School of the Relational Approach Evolutionary and institutional conceptions; Relational concept of action analyzed in spatial perspective; Interactive and organizational learning; Evolutionary and innovation issues. Bathelt & Glückler (2002; 2003); Glückler & Bathelt (2003); Gertler (1993; 1995); Grabher (1993; 2002); Maskell & Malmberg (1999); Malmberg & Maskell (2002).

Source: The authors (2018), based on Bathelt (2006)

In this way, the relational thinking was gradually consolidating the REG. Bathelt and Glückler (2003) presented a paper summarizing the background called the second evolutionary stage of REG. This stage followed a transition in Germany in which Economic Geography contributed to consolidate the so-called new REG paradigm. Economic Geography in the German school was influenced by two important paradigms: Länderkunde (the science of description and regionnal synthesis) and Raumwissenschaft (Spatial Science), which generated the first transition. That phase was strongly influen-ced by the works of Isard (1956, 1966) from the American Economic Geography (Bathelt & Glückler, 2003).

Table 3 shows a line of changes in which space stops being an object and becomes a perspective. Thus, it became an object of knowledge. As well, the conception of action and theories used in research shifted the axis. The object of research becomes a decontextualization of the principles of socioeconomic changes in the space, supported by an epistemology of critical and evolutionary realism, abandoning the search for ge- neral explanatory or deterministic laws.

Table 3 Changing research designs in the paradigms of German economic geography 

Dimensions of research design Economic Geography in Länderkunde Relational Science (or spatial analysis) Raumwissenschaft REG
Conception of space Space as object and causal factor Space as object and causal factor Space as a perspective (Geographical lens)
Object of knowledge Specific economic-space formations of a landscape Spatially manifested consequences of action (structure) Contextual economic relations (social practice, process)
Conception of action Environmental determinism/possibilism Atomistic: methodological individualism Relational: network theory, embeddedness perspective
Epistemological perspective Realism/ naturalism Neo-positivism Critical rationalism Critical realism, Evolutionary perspective
Research goal Ideographic understanding of the nature of a landscape Discovery of spatial laws of economic behavior De-contextualization of principles of socio-economic exchange in spatial perspective

Source: Bathelt & Glückler (2003)

The changes presented in Table 3 continued to form the second evolutionary stage in REG research. Bathelt and Glückler (2003), drawing on Storper’s (1997) work, introduced four core concepts or ions (according to the authors’ nomenclature) for analysis in Economic Geography, namely, Organization, Evolution, Innovation, and Interaction. In this reformulation, Storper (1997) conceptualized the so-called "Holy Trinity" (Technology, Organization, and Territory) which served as the starting point for the REG paradigm proposed by Bathelt and Glückler (2003).

Five dimensions are highlighted in the second phase of REG (see Table 3): Design of space (space as perspective); Object of knowledge (contextual economic relations - social practice, process); Conception of action (network theory and embeddedness); Epistemological perspective (evolutionary perspective), and Research objective (de-contextualization of principles of socioeconomic exchange in spatial perspective - that is, alteration of explanatory framework of socioeconomic changes based on spatial perspective) (Bathelt & Glückler, 2003).

Although researchers acknowledge that the context influences the economic action and present studies focused on the dynamics of spaces within "Relational Thinking" (Bathelt, 2006), even so, few researchers directly conceptualize REG in the papers currently published. Most of the papers specify fundamentals, epistemological bases, and origins using different conceptions and theories to derive its relational analyses. The lack of conceptualization reinforces the main criticism on REG, that the relational concept has a high level of abstraction (Sunley, 2008; Sanz-Ibáñez & Antón Clavé, 2014). Most authors refer to it as relational thinking, relational perspective or relational approaches. Nevertheless, they coincide that the dynamics of relationships is the object of REG, and that object must be included in space. Table 4 presents a brief synthesis of how authors have expressed the relational thinking.

According to Bathelt and Glückler (2003) the objective research in REG is based on three major propositions:

  • ✓ Context - From a structural perspective, economic agents are immersed in an environment of specific social and spatial relations (Granovetter, 1985);

  • ✓ Path-dependence - From a dynamic perspective, contextualization creates a dependence on the trajectory, since past actions condition/ direct future actions (Nelson & Winter, 1982);

  • ✓ Contingency - Economic actions are open and often unpredictable systems (Sayer, 1992). Economic action starts from human action and does not always follow pre-established patterns with a degree of contingency.

Thus, fundamentally, REG examines the space from the actions that human relations generate on the production systems which, in turn, influence the organization and the territorial development. Sanz-Ibáñez and Antón Clavé (2014) based on Bathelt and Glückler (2011), and Storper (1997) point out that REG focuses on: organization, concern with the social and spatial, with the division and integration of work; evolution, positive and negative impacts of historical structures, processes and events in current decisions; innovation, processes creation and diffusion of knowledge, as well as, the effects of technological changes; interaction, the interactions among economic agents and the formal and informal institutions.

A key point for the development of tourism as an economic activity is entrepreneurship. Vale, Amâncio and Lima (2006) consider three categories of entrepreneurs related to organizational networks or productive arrangements: class-ical entrepreneur (an independent enterprise), utilitarian collective entrepreneur (action in a sectorial network with a single goal), and sectoral collective entrepreneur (action in a sectoral network with multiple goals). A better performance in tourism activity can be obtained based on sectoral collective entrepreneurs.

Table 4 Definitions of Relational Thinking 

Definitions Authors
Relational refers to a specific mode of economic coordination or governance based on strong, long-term, reciprocal relationships. Typically, these relationships are informal, face-to-face, collaborative and cooperative, characterized by the exchange of knowledge and a high degree of mutual trust. Dyer & Singh (1998); Capello & Faggian (2005); Jones, Hesterly & Borgatti (1997); Rutten (2004)
The relational approach is a link between cultural research and economic focus. Ettlinger (2001)
The relational analysis is not a rigid analytical framework or an explicit prospect for future research, but it is a methodology and a starting point for empirical work. Dicken, Kelly, Olds & Yeung (2001)
The relational perspective is a conceptual starting point. Dicken & Malmberg (2001)
Actors and its dynamic processes of changes and development generated by their relations are the basic units of relational perspective. Boggs & Rantisi (2003)
REG is not a single standard theory, but a way to observe the space. The relational point of view rests on the assumptions of context, path-dependence, and the contingency of economic action. The objective is to discover a new way to formulate research questions in economic geography different from those used in traditional regional science to obtain different answers. Bathelt & Glücker (2003)
REG integrates the economic and social, cultural, institutional, and political aspects of human action. Bathelt & Glückler (2003)
The Relational Perspective in economic geography is particularly suited to conceptualize economic and political action from a spatial perspective. In opposition to the traditional view, this approach allows us to analyze the consequences of global interdependencies and their relationships with the processes of local concentration and specialization. Bathelt (2003; 2005a; 2005b; 2006)
REG is not a carefully defined analytical framework; is a dispersed set of theories and ideas that share some characteristics and differ from certain aspects. Bathelt (2006)
The Relational Perspective is based on a micro-level approach, focusing on actors in those economic and social processes that result in agglomeration, economic specialization, unequal development. Bathelt (2006)
REG is concerned with social and spatial, division and integration of work, with the positive and negative impact of historical structures, processes and events on today's decisions, such as the processes of creation and dissemination of knowledge, as well as, its effects on technological change; and finally, the interactions between the economic agents and the formal and informal institutions that stimulate and restrict them. Bathelt & Glückler (2003, 2011)
Relational perspectives are based on micro-level approaches, focusing on actors involved in economic and social processes that result in unequal outcomes such as levels of agglomeration, economic specialization, or development. Barrutia, Echebarria, Hartmann, & Apaolaza-Ibáñez (2013)
The counterpoint of the relational perspective provides an adequate spatial analogy to conceptualize cities by the level of their relationships. It conceptualizes the urban relations both linked and fragmented. Therefore, it designs cities according to spatial and temporal randomness in an inherent way that puts in the foreground the ruptures and the asymmetries of complex fragments instead of smooth totalities. O’Callaghan (2012)

Source: The authors (2018)

Entrepreneurship is a contextualized and contingent human action and, from the four ions defined by Bathelt and Glückler (2003) - Innovation, Organization, Interact-ion, and Evolution - generates economic activity for territorial development. In this sense, economic science identifies entrepreneurship as a vital element for development, also, Schumpeter (1961) considered that entrepreneurs play a leading role in the economic evolution. Figure 1 shows the transition from relational thinking towards the paradigm of REG according to Bathelt and Glückler (2003) proposition.

Source: The authors (2018)

Figure 1 Relational Economic Geography (REG) proposition 

Following this line, space as a socially constructed entity by human action is economic action. Thus, contextual economic relations are the process of social practices (intentions, strategies, and activities of actors) which in turn is the object of knowledge of REG (Butler, 2003).

Human action gains prominence because it creates or limits opportunities. The actions occur in a space that accumulated knowledge, habits, and other elements, therefore influencing future decisions, i.e., path dependence. However, this set, (human action + context + path dependence) still suffers another influence, i.e., the contingency of human action itself and the context, since the economic activity is not always predictable (Bathelt & Glückler, 2011; Sanz-Ibáñez & Antón Clavé, 2014).

3 TOURISM DESTINATIONS ANALYZED AS PRODUCTIVE AGGLOMERATIONS (NETWORKS, DISTRICTS, CLUSTER, LPA) FROM REG PERSPECTIVE

It is consensual among researchers that tourism is a space activity, socially constructed. Therefore, it evolves (Seaton & Bennett, 1996; Ringer, 1998; Saarinen, 2001; Shaw & Williams, 2004). Also, the formation of organizational networks and governance mechanisms are considered ways of supporting the local development in tourism destinations (Della Corte & Sciarelli, 2012).

Tourism destinations have both economic and social functions, with high complexity and interdependence of actors. Also, tourism activities are characterized by great diversity. The analysis of the operational way of the tourism destination and its typology of productive agglomeration contribute to developing planning and management tools more suited to the local and regional reality. Therefore, it improves the level of distribution of tourism activity benefits and the sustainability of available resources (Buhalis, 2000).

Studies on the evolution and performance of destinations using conventional models of tourism geography have evidenced weaknesses as explanatory tools, emphasizing the need for new categories and perspective of analysis (Brouder & Eriksson, 2013; Williams, 2013; Sanz-Ibánez & Antón Clavé, 2014).

Tourism destinations can be organized in different ways. They represent productive agglomerations that convert local synergies into competitive advantages (Costa & Souto-Maior, 2006). At this point it becomes important to look at the boundaries between some typologies such as networks, districts, cluster, and local productive arrangements (LPAs), to verify whether REG can replace the analysis of tourism destinations based on these theories or if it complements them.

A tourism destination is commonly seen as a set of institutions and actors, located in a physical or virtual space, but with relations that challenge the traditional dichotomy of production-consumption. Indeed, it is a unit of action and production, where several stakeholders interact producing the tourism experience (Saraniemi & Kylänen, 2010; Pearce, 2014). In tourism research, the term agglomeration is usually used, since the development of this activity at the micro level generates some firms territorially located and often articulated seeking the development of the activity. This categorization comes from Porter (1999), which defines cluster as a geographically concentrated grouping of interrelated firms and correlated institutions in an area, linked by common and complementary elements. That is, tourism agglomerations are what Porter calls clusters. However, due to its comprehensive nature, industrial districts, and local productive arrangements (LPAs) have also been included in tourism cluster studies.

The border between networks, districts, clusters, and LPAs is sometimes difficult to establish. The fine line between an LPA and a cluster can be considered the greater geographical and sectoral concentration that the clusters have in comparison with productive agglomerations, as well as, the better collective ability to deal with the market (Schmitz, 1997; Silva, 2014). LPAs are agglomerations of organizations, with large numbers of small firms, which use a joint action, cooperating to achieve better competitiveness and development (Pyke & Sengenberger, 1993; Caporali & Volker, 2004; Costa et al., 2012).

On the other hand, Dini (1997) distinguishes industrial districts from networks because he considers networks have a limited number of firms, participants are identified, the composition has low variation and participants are not necessarily in the same territory. Particularly, it is necessary to emphasize the excluding nature of networks when considering tourism destinations in their entirety. The United Nations Development Organization defines a business network as a permanent strategic alliance between a limited and clearly defined group of independent firms, which collaborate to achieve common medium and long-term goals, aimed at developing the competitiveness of the participants (ONUDI, 1999). In this sense, a network is a set of preferred, selected, members. Therefore, it has an exclusionary character that does not apply to the analysis of an integral tourism destination (Camagni, 1991; Ceglie et al, 1999).

On the other hand, theoretical-empirical studies on districts have been the focus of researchers since the 1970s. In that period, a major economic recession led several countries to seek solutions many of which relied on the formation of an industrial district (Pyke et al., 1990). In this sense, there are many organizations located in a geographical area (co-location), with different structures and sizes participating in the different production stages for the generation of a homogeneous product (Pyke et al., 1990). Another factor making tourism destinations closer to industrial districts is the massive participation of small firms, characteristic emphasized by several authors of both industrial districts and tourism (Hjalager, 2000). Also, two other prominent characteristics in the district theoretical framework bring it closer to tourism destinations: the existence of public and private local institutions that support the economic agents, and the existence of a common cultural and social context that links these economic agents, generating codes of common behavior (Pyke et al., 1990).

Hjalager (2000) was one of the authors that contributed to the establishment of the typology "Tourism Districts." Her study identifies five determinants to qualify a tourism district: interdependence of firms; flexible firm boundaries; cooperative competition; trust in sustained collaboration; a community culture with supportive public policies. Likewise, from the perspective of networks, tourism districts as productive space arrangement is also grounded in REG.

The associative character of cooperative companies seeking competitiveness is explicitly a feature included in relational thinking. Also, the collective learning generated by the group leads to path dependence and spatial constraints put the participants in a specific context (Bathelt, 2006).

The re-reading of this productive reality through REG lens enhance some characteristics. The existence of co-location is pointed out by the REG scholars as a relational facilitator (Bathelt, 2006). The agents subject to a special context leads them to operate under specific institutional and social conditions from which they cannot be easily separated. This feature is also considered within the REG approach (Polanyi, 1957; Granovetter, 1985). Within the five Hjalager’s (2000) determinants defined for tourism districts, Amin and Cohendet (2004) consider, in terms of relational thinking, that relational proximity enables close social interaction and becomes a source of competitiveness.

Cluster classification deserves a special attention since this construct is one of the most studied productive forms. The concept defined by Porter (1988) finds a practical problem in the tourism activity. Activity within tourism destinations is diffuse, which makes it difficult to accurately measure the grouping and categorization, thus raising doubts about tourism cluster classification (Amato, 1999; Ivars Baidal et al., 2014). However, the territorial and endogenous model of regional development is still considered the most appropriate. It is possible to choose productive specialization (tourism) as a representative element of the explanations of local and regional economic development (Silva, 2006).

This imprecision has led to the use of cluster in a broad sense for any productive arrangement, and many times confusing it with the concept of district. The two forms have similarities, but a cluster entails a degree of geographic concentration, which in tourism destinations does not always occur. The most used measure to verify this concentration has been the Location Quotient (LQ) and the number of sectorial jobs to define the importance of the activity for a region.

However, the literature does not indicate any reference value for a tourism destination to be considered a cluster. Another fact that weighs on this perspective is highlighted by Amato (1999). The author points out the difficulty of "clusterization" since it is a productive chain composed of a series of complementary services to the main tourism products, making it even more difficult to separate clearly the categories or agglomerates (clustering).

Ivars Baidal et al. (2014) emphasize that this configuration requires preconditions, such as regional or innovation policies, company initiatives or associations, the existence of a unifying project, or a person with leadership and mobilization capacity. In any case, the cluster perspective is based on a collective efficiency (Porter, 1988) generated from the interrelationship between the agents, circumscribed in a geographic space. There is a coincidence with the perspective of REG since relationships are a key condition for obtaining this collective efficiency.

In the LPA approach, the territory has a specific scope of analysis and action, where the productive, innovative, and cooperative process occurs (Cassiolato, Lastres & Maciel, 2013). This type of agglomeration has an important degree of embeddedness, can have different forms of governance, generates and shares knowledge, providing dynamism and innovation to the region in which it is located (Silva, 2014). Hoffmann and Campos (2013) highlight four features of LPAs and that have been much discussed by the scholars: trust, skilled labor, cooperation, and the role of institutions. From a relational thinking perspective, this is human action in its context generating economic action (Bathelt, 2006). Thus, REG offers an angle to study the sum of the action of these resources in the territorial dimension and the reflecting of human activity on local competitiveness.

Table 5 presents tourism destination characteristics considering whether they are met in the analysis through the different forms of productive agglomerations. Also, it shows if the REG background would be able to achieve these characteristics, considering its theoretical foundations applied to tourism destination analysis.

Table 5 Tourism destinations characteristics analyzed from different perspectives 

Tourism destinations characteristics Network District Cluster LPA REG
Broad geographic boundaries X X
The existence of relational proximity X X X X X
Interdependence among organizations X X X X X
The existence of shared goal X X X
The existence of governance structure X X X
Dependence of infrastructure or urban services X X X X X
High dependence of local resources (natural and cultural) X X X
Dependence of affinity by the local population to the activity X
Micro/Mesa level of analysis X X X X X
High dependence of context and social environmental X X X
Path dependence X X
Existence of co-creation experiences X X
High degree of heterogeneity in the economic activities X X X X
Selection of participants with an inclusive character (open to all of the destination) X X
Not hierarchical X X X
Final product is unique (Tourism destination) X X
The existence of public institutions and policies to support economic agents X X X
High degree of common culture among the agents X X X X
The existence of cooperation-competitive X X X X X
Diverse forms of spatial arrangements and different level of concentration of firms X
High participation of SMEs X X X X X
Co-Marketing X X
Social and business associations X X X X X
Context X X X X
Co-Evolution X X X X X
Innovation facilitator X X X X X

Source: The authors (2018)

The need to adapt some traditional concepts to tourism is evident, as is the case of agglomeration, networks, district, or cluster, and to translate some theories to the practice of tourism destinations, mainly to give clear limits regarding clustering and conformation of districts (Judd, 1995; Weidenfeld, Butler & Williams, 2010; Sanz-Ibáñez & Antón Clavé, 2014). Given the above, it can be stated that REG's contribution to the analysis of tourism destinations is visible. However, there are questions that remain such as: Does REG replace the perspective of networks, districts, clusters, and arrangements or does it complement it? Can REG be applied in any of these productive arrangements or are there limitations?

It can be seen in Table 5 that the more the analysis of the destination tends to the micro scale, the better the characteristics of tourism destinations are met. Besides, REG demonstrates that it can include all the characteristics present in tourism destinations thus allowing for a complete analysis.

Some authors have sought a specific typology of agglomeration for tourism, coining terms, and definitions such as: Tourism District (Hjalager, 2000; Baggio, 2008); Tourism Cluster (Costa et al, 2012); Local Tourism System (Capone, 2004, 2006; Maulet, 2006; Lazzeretti & Capone, 2008); or Dynamic Tourism Destination (Sanz-Ibáñez & Antón Clavé, 2014). Thus, it is observed that tourism destinations move towards their own typology, and identity as a productive arrangement and unit of spatial analysis, which apparently seems to be a mixture of networks, districts, clusters, and LPAs, but certainly based on relational thinking, since it establishes a network of relations between actors that compete for the division of the market, while cooperating to develop it (Della Corte & Sciarelli, 2012).

The classic destination analysis is based on models of tourism competitiveness such as those of Porter (1990), Dwyer and Kim (2003), Ritchie and Crouch (2003), as well as the analysis by resources and capacities based on Barney (1989), and by productive agglomerations. However, these perspectives of analysis face the challenge of including a more active relationship between the different actors that form this sub-sector.

The internal and external cooperation-competitive relations (coopetition) to the tourism destination lead to the improvement of collective efficiency, the formation of learning and innovation regions (Ivars Baidal et al., 2014), but, in this sense, a typology of productive systems for the tourism destinations is still not clearly defined.

Complementing the previous discussions should be noted that Pearce (2014) recently has proposed an integrative conceptual framework of tourism destinations, by synthetizing elements from industrial districts, networks, clusters, systems, and social structures. His proposal integrates the geographic dimension (space and place), the mode of production dimension (structure, behavior, and actors), and the dynamic dimension (structure and driving factors). Notably, the author emphasizes that the relationship between these dimensions and their factors generate the complexity, adaptability, and evolution of destinations. However, the author warns that there is still a long way to go in refining each of the elements that make up his proposal, he reinforces that it is a path that points to a proper classification for tourism destinations (Pearce, 2014) and, as can be seen, transits through the fundamentals of Evolutionary and Relational Economic Geography.

4 ANALYSIS OF RESULTS

The arguments and rationale presented show that relational analysis is necessary for regional or local economic studies, and especially for studies of tourism destinations. The REG has in its center the human action and is based on the contingency, context, and path dependence, which is based on interaction, innovation, organization, and evolution ions. These elements conform the entrepreneurship, which generates the economic action immersed in an environment of coopetition for the formation and development of tourism destinations as an integral product. The sum of these considerations indicates the integration of this knowledge using REG for regional analyses.

Human action permeates and forms the foundations of REG that support the formation and evolution of integrated tourism destinations. However, the way REG will materialize in destination planning, as an analysis instrument and tool to assist in the decision-making process, is still undefined. The understanding of coopetition relation-ships can be a way of analyzing tourism destinations considering the perspectives of REG and enabling the development of tools for empirical relational analysis. This form of behavior fits into the formation of value networks that include competitors, complementors, customers, and suppliers (Brandenburg & Nalebuff, 1996).

Another issue arising from the discussion is that the foundations of REG interact with each other, acting in their formation, being a cycle without clear beginning. Tourism destinations are built upon natural, cultural, social, political, and economic resources which affect the context and trajectory that, in turn, condition the human action. But, can this order of formation be reversed?

Another question is to know whether REG should be used as a new competing paradigm in the analysis of tourism destinations or considered as a complementary paradigm to existing ones; and how this complement could be used in the theoretical-empirical analyses adding to knowledge. Finally, it is questioned whether mature theories should be revised to include social relations in their theoretical foundations.

These questions are in line with numerous criticisms of REG, which suggests that despite its acclaimed use, its evolution towards a consolidated theory has not occurred. The same situation arises with the concepts of agglomerations such as cluster/district/networks / LPAs that continue to receive criticism for the thin line that separates them and the lack of clear criteria to differentiate these typologies and apply them in the analysis of tourism destinations.

The best way of framing tourism destinations regarding the typology of agglomeration is still not clear. However, REG can be used to analyze destinations regardless of their form of productive organization since it encompasses all destination characteristics. Moreover, the object of analysis becomes the human actions and relationships, and these would occur regardless of the productive agglomeration considered.

5 FINAL REMARKS

This paper has critically examined relational thinking, bringing to the academic debate the REG proposal, its origin and foundation, with the purpose of encouraging the scientific community to join the effort to develop a methodology of analysis and empirical application that would enable the use of this approach. This study carried out a compilation of papers and presents a consistent literature review on relational theory, articulating these concepts with tourism. We have discussed the use of REG in tourism destination studies since some destination characteristics rely on the interdependence of the actors to become an integral product (Della Corte & Sciarelli, 2012).

In this debate we presented some critical points of REG that are pointed out in the study developed by Sanz-Ibáñez and Antón Clavé (2014), such as: lack of specificity and the extreme abstraction pointed out by Sunley (2008); little theorizing about power relations (Yeung, 2005); focus on firms rather than individuals in micro-level analysis (Ettlinger, 2003); and low emphasis on non-local flows and relationships (Yeung, 2005).

However, it should be noted that se-veral authors have worked within relational perspectives. The role of the local and global interaction between economic and non-economic actors is undoubtedly a factor that can either help or hinder the development of places (Bathelt & Glückler, 2011).

It seems that REG can contribute to the analysis of tourism destinations, however, more in-depth theoretical grounding, analysis tools, and specific methodologies are needed. In this way, this diffuse approach could achieve the status of a paradigm and make a useful contribution to regional and local analysis, as well as management support for public policies. REG can also contribute to a much-debated topic among scholars, i.e., the establishment of a typology of productive agglomeration with evident characteristics as to its form of classification, clearing up doubts if we consider the destination from the perspective of a network, district, cluster, or LPA.

The entrepreneurial action generated by the four ions defined by Bathelt and Glückler (2003) - Innovation, Organization, Interaction, and Evolution, whose apex is made by human action based on the foundations of REG (context, contingency and path-dependence) system that can lead to regional competitiveness.

However, whether is the context that forms and develops the tourism destination or the other way around, being the human action and path dependence reflex of this context, are questions to be further addressed by REG. It seems that it is a cycle that can be started from any point, depending on the previous political, natural, economic, and social condition that the environment offers.

To conclude, we suggest that from relational thinking further studies prioritize the creation of a typology with its own criteria for classification and analysis of tourism destinations, in order to establish mechanisms for their practical application. This can be achieved either by adapting the various existing theories in the industrial sector and the economy, or by creating new forms, but keeping in mind the peculiarities of tourism.

Thus, it is considered that REG can be used to analyze a tourism destination in any form of agglomeration because it has space as a perspective and not as an object or causal factor. This means that the object of knowledge is the economic context of relationships, a fact that occurs in any productive arrangement. Finally, it can be concluded that the REG can be a theoretical basis for creating tools for analysis, classification, and monitoring the influence of relational proximity and its influence on the development of localities and regions. These tools can contribute both to take REG out of the abstraction and to give substance to a new theorization applied to tourism.

REFERENCES

Allen, J. (1997). Economies of power and space. Geographies of economies, London, New York, Sidney: Arnold 59-70. [ Links ]

Amin, A. (ed) (1994). Post-Fordismo. Oxford. Cambridge: MA Blackwell. [ Links ]

Amin, A. (1998). Globalisation and regional development: a relational perspective. Competition & Change, 3(1-2), 145-165. [ Links ]

Amin, A., & Cohendet, P. (2004). Architectures of knowledge: Firms, capabilities, and communities. Oxford University Press on Demand. [ Links ]

Amin, A., & Thrift, N. (2000). What kind of economic theory for what kind of economic geography? Antipode, 32(1), 4-9. [ Links ]

Amin, A.; Massey, D. & Thrift, N. (2003). Decentering the national: a radical approach to regional inequality. London: Catalyst. [ Links ]

Baggio, R. (2008). Network analysis of a tourism destination (Unpublished doctoral dissertation). Australia: University of Queensland. [ Links ]

Barney, J. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of management, 17(1), 99-120. [ Links ]

Barrutia, J. M., Echebarria, C., Apaolaza-Ibáñez, V., & Hartmann, P. (2014). Informal and formal sources of knowledge as drivers of regional innovation: digging a little further into complexity. Environment and Planning A, 46(2), 414-432. [ Links ]

Bathelt, H., & Glückler, J. (2002). Wirtschaftsgeographie: Ökonomische Beziehungen in räumlicher Perspektive (Economic geography: Economic relations in spatial perspective). Stuttgart: UTB-Ulmer. [ Links ]

Bathelt, H., & Glückler, J. (2003). Toward a relational economic geography. Journal of economic geography, 3(2), 117-144. [ Links ]

Bathelt, H., & Glückler, J. (2011). The relational economy: Geographies of knowing and learning. Oxford University Press. [ Links ]

Bathelt, H. (2003). Geographies of production: growth regimes in spatial perspective 1-innovation, institutions and social systems. Progress in Human Geography, 27(6), 763-778. [ Links ]

Bathelt, H. (2005). Geographies of production: growth regimes in spatial perspective (II)-knowledge creation and growth in clusters. Progress in human geography, 29(2), 204-216. [ Links ]

Bathelt, H. (2005). Cluster relations in the media industry: Exploring the'distanced neighbour'paradox in Leipzig. Regional Studies, 39(1), 105-127. [ Links ]

Bathelt, H. (2006). Geographies of production: growth regimes in spatial perspective 3-toward a relational view of economic action and policy. Progress in human geography, 30(2), 223-236. [ Links ]

Boggs, J. S., & Rantisi, N. M. (2003). The ‘relational turn’in economic geography. Journal of economic geography, 3(2), 109-116. [ Links ]

Boschma, R. A., & Frenken, K. (2006). Why is economic geography not an evolutionary science? Towards an evolutionary economic geography. Journal of economic geography, 6(3), 273-302. [ Links ]

Boschma, R., & Frenken, K. (2010). The spatial evolution of innovation networks. A proximity perspective. The handbook of evolutionary economic geography, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 120-135. [ Links ]

Boschma, R., & Martin, R. (2007). Constructing an evolutionary economic geography. Journal of Economic Geography, 7(5), 537-548. [ Links ]

Boschma, R., & Martin, R. (2010). The aims and scope of evolutionary economic geography. The handbook of evolutionary economic geography, 3-39. [ Links ]

Brandenburger, A., & Nalebuff, B. J. (1996). Co-Opetition (Currency Doubleday, New York). [ Links ]

Brouder, P., & Eriksson, R. H. (2013). Tourism evolution: On the synergies of tourism studies and evolutionary economic geography. Annals of Tourism Research, 43, 370-389. [ Links ]

Buhalis, D. (2000). Marketing the competitive destination of the future. Tourism management, 21(1), 97-116. [ Links ]

Butler, R. W. (2004). The tourism area life cycle in the twenty-first century. In A. A. Lew, C. M. Hall, & A. M. Williams (Eds.), A companion to tourism (pp. 159_169). Oxford: Blackwell. [ Links ]

Camagni, R. (1991). Innovation Networks: Spatial Perspectives. London: Belhaven-Pinter. [ Links ]

Capello, R., & Faggian, A. (2005). Collective learning and relational capital in local innovation processes. Regional studies, 39(1), 75-87. [ Links ]

Capone, F. (2004). Regional competitiveness in tourist local systems. 44º European Congress of the European Regional Science Association, Regions and Fiscal Federalism, University of Oporto. [ Links ]

Capone, F. (2006). Systemic approaches for the analysis of tourism destination: towards the tourist local systems. Tourism local systems and networking, 7-23. [ Links ]

Caporali, R., & Volker, P. (2004). Metodologia de Desenvolvimento de Arranjos Produtivos Locais: projeto PROMOS-SEBRAE-BID versão 2.0. Brasília, Sebrae. [ Links ]

Ceglie, G., Clara, M., & Dini, M. (1999). Cluster and network development projects in developing countries: lessons learned through the UNIDO experience. Boosting innovation: The cluster approach, 269-292. [ Links ]

Clark, G. L. (1983). Fluctuations and rigidities in local labor markets. Part 2: reinterpreting contracts. Environment and Planning A, 15(3), 365-377. [ Links ]

Clark, G., & Tracey, P. (2004). Global competitiveness and innovation: an agent-centred perspective. Basingstoke, New York: Palgrave Macmillan. [ Links ]

Coe, N. M., & Bunnell, T. G. (2003). ‘Spatializing’knowledge communities: towards a conceptualization of transnational innovation networks. Global networks, 3(4), 437-456. [ Links ]

Coe, N. M., Hess, M., Yeung, H. W. C., Dicken, P., & Henderson, J. (2004). ‘Globalizing’regional development: a global production networks perspective. Transactions of the Institute of British geographers, 29(4), 468-484. [ Links ]

Costa, H.A.; Costa, A.C. & Miranda, N.S.J. (2012). Arranjos Produtivos Locais (APL) no Turismo: estudo sobre a Competitividade e o Desenvolvimento Local na Costa dos Corais-AL. Revista acadêmica Observatório de Inovação do Turismo, 7(1). [ Links ]

Davidson, R., & Maitland, R. (1997). Tourism destinations. Hodder & Stoughton. [ Links ]

Della Corte, V., & Sciarelli, M. (2012). Can coopetition be source of competitive advantage for strategic networks. Corporate Ownership and Control, 12(1), 363-379. [ Links ]

Dicken, P. (2005). Tangled webs: transnational production networks and regional integration. Spatial Aspects Concerning Economic Structures Working Paper (SPACES) 2005-04, Faculty of Geography, Philipps- University of Marburg. [ Links ]

Dicken, P., & Malmberg, A. (2001). Firms in territories: a relational perspective. Economic geography, 77(4), 345-363. [ Links ]

Dicken, P., Kelly, P. F., Olds, K., & Wai‐Chung Yeung, H. (2001). Chains and networks, territories and scales: towards a relational framework for analysing the global economy. Global networks, 1(2), 89-112. [ Links ]

Dini, M. (1997). Enfoques conceptuales para el estudio de pequeñas y medianas empresas. Santiago de Chile. CEPAL. [ Links ]

Domareski Ruiz, T. C., Fumi Chim Miki, A., & Gândara, J. M. (2014). A geografia econômica evolutiva como perspectiva de análise da dinâmica dos destinos turísticos. Caderno Virtual de Turismo, 14(3). [ Links ]

Dyer, J. H., & Singh, H. (1998). The relational view: Cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage. Academy of management review, 23(4), 660-679. [ Links ]

Dwyer, L., & Kim, C. (2003). Destination competitiveness: determinants and indicators. Current issues in tourism, 6(5), 369-414. [ Links ]

Ettlinger, N. (2001). Cultural Economic geography and a relational and microspace approach to trust, rationalities, networks, and change in collaborative workplaces. Journal of Economic Geography, 3, 145-171. [ Links ]

Faulconbridge, J. R. (2006). Stretching tacit knowledge beyond a local fix? Global spaces of learning in advertising professional service firms. Journal of Economic Geography, 6(4), 517-540. [ Links ]

Frenken, K., Van Oort, F., & Verburg, T. (2007). Related variety, unrelated variety and regional economic growth. Regional studies, 41(5), 685-697. [ Links ]

Gertler, M. S. (1995). “Being there”: proximity, organization, and culture in the development and adoption of advanced manufacturing technologies. Economic geography, 71(1), 1-26. [ Links ]

Grabher, G. (1993). Rediscovering the social in the economics of interfirm relations. The embedded firm: On the socioeconomics of industrial networks, 1-31. [ Links ]

Grabher, G. (2002). Cool projects, boring institutions: temporary collaboration in social context. Regional studies, 36(3), 205-214. [ Links ]

Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness. American journal of sociology, 91(3), 481-510. [ Links ]

Henderson, J., Dicken, P., Hess, M., Coe, N., & Yeung, H. W. C. (2002). Global production networks and the analysis of economic development. Review of international political economy, 9(3), 436-464. [ Links ]

Hjalager, A. M. (2000). Tourism destinations and the concept of industrial districts. Tourism and Hospitality Research, 2(3), 199-213. [ Links ]

Hoffmann, V.E., & de Souza Campos, L. M. (2013). Instituições de suporte, serviços e desempenho: um estudo em aglomeração turística de Santa Catarina. RAC-Revista de Administração Contemporânea, 17(1). [ Links ]

Isard, W. (1956). Location and space-economy. [ Links ]

Isard, W. (1966). Methods of regional analysis (Vol. 4). Рипол Классик. [ Links ]

Jones, C., Hesterly, W. S., & Borgatti, S. P. (1997). A general theory of network governance: Exchange conditions and social mechanisms. Academy of management review, 22(4), 911-945. [ Links ]

Judd, D. R. (1995). Promoting tourism in US cities. Tourism Management, 16(3), 175-187. [ Links ]

Laws, E. (1995). Tourism destination management: issues, analysis and policies. Routledge. [ Links ]

Lazzeretti, L., & Capone, F. (2008). Mapping and analysing local tourism systems in Italy, 1991-2001. Tourism Geographies, 10(2), 214-232. [ Links ]

Lee, R. (2002). ‘Nice maps, shame about the theory’? Thinking geographically about the economic. Progress in Human Geography, 26(3), 333-355. [ Links ]

Malmberg, A., & Maskell, P. (2002). The elusive concept of localization economies: towards a knowledge-based theory of spatial clustering. Environment and planning A, 34(3), 429-449. [ Links ]

Maskell, P., & Malmberg, A. (1999). The Competitiveness of Firms and Regions: ‘Ubiquitification’and the Importance of Localized Learning. European Urban and Regional Studies, 6(1), 9-25. [ Links ]

Massey, D. (1985). New directions in space. In Social relations and spatial structures (pp. 9-19). Palgrave, London. [ Links ]

Massey, D. (2004). Geographies of responsibility. Geografiska Annaler: Series B, Human Geography, 86(1), 5-18. [ Links ]

Maulet, G. (2006). A framework to identify a localised tourism system. Tourism local systems and networking, 25-41. [ Links ]

Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (1982). An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change (Cambridge, MA: Belknap/Harvard University Press). [ Links ]

Nelson, R. R. (2009). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Harvard University Press. [ Links ]

O'Callaghan, C. (2012). Contrapuntal urbanisms: towards a postcolonial relational geography. Environment and Planning A, 44(8), 1930-1950. [ Links ]

Overman, H. G. (2004). Can we learn anything from economic geography proper? Journal of Economic Geography, 4(5), 501-516. [ Links ]

Polanyi, K. (1957). The economy as instituted process. Trade and market in the early empires, Glenco: Free Press, 243-70. [ Links ]

Porter, M. E. (1990). The competitive advantage of nations. Harvard business review, 68(2), 73-93. [ Links ]

Porter, M E. (1998). On competition. Boston, MA: Harvard Business Review Press. [ Links ]

Porter, M. E. (1999). Competição: estratégias competitivas essenciais. Gulf Professional Publishing. [ Links ]

Pearce, D. G. (2014). Toward an integrative conceptual framework of destinations. Journal of Travel Research, 53(2), 141-153. [ Links ]

Pyke, F., Becattini, G., & Sengenberger, W. (Eds.). (1990). Industrial districts and inter-firm co-operation in Italy. International Institute for Labour Studies, 125-154. [ Links ]

Pyke, F. & Sengenberger, W. (1993). Los distritos industriales y las pequenas empresas: distritos industriales y regeneracion economica local. v. III. Ministério de Trabajo y Seguridad Social. [ Links ]

Randelli, F., Romei, P., & Tortora, M. (2014). An evolutionary approach to the study of rural tourism: The case of Tuscany. Land Use Policy, 38, 276-281. [ Links ]

Ringer, G. (1998). Introduction. In Destinations: Cultural Landscapes of Tourism, edited by G. Ringer. London: Routledge, 1-13. [ Links ]

Ritchie, J. B., & Crouch, G. I. (2003). The competitive destination: A sustainable tourism perspective. Cabi. [ Links ]

Rutten, R. (2004). Inter-firm knowledge creation: A re-appreciation of embeddedness from a relational perspective. European Planning Studies, 12(5), 659-673. [ Links ]

Saarinen, J. (2004). ‘Destinations in change’ The transformation process of tourism destinations. Tourist studies, 4(2), 161-179. [ Links ]

Shaw, G., & Williams, A. M. (2004). Tourism and tourism spaces. Sage. [ Links ]

Sanz-Ibáñez, C., & Anton Clavé, S. (2014). The evolution of destinations: Towards an evolutionary and relational economic geography approach. Tourism Geographies, 16(4), 563-579. [ Links ]

Saraniemi, S., & Kylänen, M. (2011). Problematizing the concept of tourism destination: An analysis of different theoretical approaches. Journal of Travel Research, 50(2), 133-143. [ Links ]

Sayer, A. (1992). Method in social science: London. Routledge. [ Links ]

Sayer, A. (2000). Realism and social science. Sage. [ Links ]

Schmitz, H. (1997). Eficiência coletiva: caminho de crescimento para a indústria de pequeno porte. Ensaios FEE, 18(2), 164-200. [ Links ]

Scott, A. J. (1988). New industrial spaces: Flexible production organization and regional development in North America and Western Europe (Vol. 3). Pion Ltd. [ Links ]

Seaton, A. V., & Bennett, M. M. (1996). The marketing of tourism products: Concepts, issues and cases. Cengage Learning EMEA. [ Links ]

Silva, P. M. (2015). Aglomerados e turismo: análise da produção científica nacional e internacional sobre o tema. Turismo-Visão e Ação, 16(2), 338-357. [ Links ]

Silva, J. A. (2006). A dimensão territorial no planejamento do desenvolvimento turístico no BrasiI: modelo do pólo de crescimento versus modelo territorialista e endógeno. Revista Turismo em Análise, 17(3), 5-23. [ Links ]

Storper, M. (1997). The regional world: territorial development in a global economy. Guilford Press. [ Links ]

Storper, M., & Walker, R. (1989). The capitalist imperative: Territory, technology, and industrial growth. Blackwell. [ Links ]

Sunley, P. (2008). Relational economic geography: a partial understanding or a new paradigm? Economic Geography, 84(1), 1-26. [ Links ]

Thrift, N. (2000a). Pandora’s box? Cultural geographies of economies. In Clark, G.L., Feldman, M.P. and Gertler, M.S., editors, The Oxford handbook of economic geography, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 689-704. [ Links ]

Thrift, N. (2000b). Performing cultures in the new economy. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 90(4), 674-692. [ Links ]

Vale, G. M.V., Amâncio, R., & Braga de Lima, J. (2006). Criação e gestão de redes: uma estratégia competitiva para empresas e regiões. Revista de Administração-RAUSP, 41(2). [ Links ]

Walker, R., & Storper, M. (1981). Capital and industrial location. Progress in Geography, 5(4), 473-509. [ Links ]

Williams, A. M. (2013). Mobilities and sustainable tourism: path-creating or path-dependent relationships? Journal of Sustainable Tourism, 21(4), 511-531. [ Links ]

Yeung, H. W. C. (1998). Capital, state and space: contesting the borderless world. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 23(3), 291-309. [ Links ]

Yeung, H. W. C. (2005). Rethinking relational economic geography. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 30(1), 37-51. [ Links ]

Received: December 14, 2017; Accepted: April 24, 2018

Adriana Fumi Chim-Miki

PhD in Tourism, Economics and Management from the University of Las Palmas de Gran Canaria, Spain. Master in Geography, Postgraduate in Environmental Management, and graduated in Business Administration by Federal University of Rio Grande (FURG), Brazil. Currently she is Associate Professor at the Faculty of Management and Accounting and, Coordinator of the Management Postgraduate Program of the Federal University of Campina Grande (UFCG), Brazil. Leader of the Research group: Coopetition Network Lab - REDES 6CO. E-mail: adriana.chimmiki@gmail.com

Thays Cristina Domareski Ruiz

Master in Tourism and Hospitality from the University of Vale do Itajaí, Santa Catarina, Brazil (UNIVALI). Bachelor in Tourism from University State of Paraná (UNIOESTE). Associate Professor, Department of Tourism, Federal University of Paraná. Researcher-collaborator in Coopetition Network Lab - REDES 6CO Research Group. E-mail: thaysdomareski@gmail.com

Creative Commons License This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License